Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

The Slow Diagrams - Intermediate Macroeconomics Analysis | ECON 202, Study notes of Economics

Material Type: Notes; Class: Intermediate Macro Analysis; Subject: Economics; University: Wellesley College; Term: Unknown 1989;

Typology: Study notes

Pre 2010

Uploaded on 08/18/2009

koofers-user-ml7
koofers-user-ml7 🇺🇸

5

(1)

10 documents

1 / 5

Toggle sidebar

This page cannot be seen from the preview

Don't miss anything!

bg1
Fall Semester ’05-’06
Akila Weerapana
Lecture 4: The Solow Diagram
I. OVERVIEW
In the last lecture, we discussed the importance of economic growth, and the importance of
models. We then derived a model of economic growth: the Solow growth model, which basi-
cally consisted of two equations: a production function and a capital accumulation equation.
In today’s lecture, we will first transform these equations into per-capita terms: in other
words write the equations in terms of output and capital per-capita. This will make the
model more tractable. We will then use these two equations to draw a diagram known as the
Solow diagram.
We will then use this diagram to do various “comparative statics” exercises where we analyze
the impact of changes in saving rates, population growth rates, the capital stock etc. on
economic growth in the short run and in the long run.
II. THE PER-CAPITA VERSION OF THE SOLOW MODEL
In order to make working with the model a little easier, we transform the model into per-
capita terms. Define the following per-capita variables y=Y
L(output per worker) and k=K
L
(capital per worker)
Note that every person is a worker in this model. I will use per-capita and per-worker
interchangeably.)
The production function can be written in per-capita terms as Y
L=KαL1α
LKα
Lαwhich
means that y=kα
The capital accumulation equation can be written in per-capita terms as well.
k=K
L
˙
k
k=˙
K
K
˙
L
L
˙
k
k=(sY δK)
Kn(sY )
Kδn
˙
k
k=(sY/L)
K/L (δ+n)(sy)
k(δ+n)
˙
k=sy (δ+n)k
This equation states that net investment per worker (the change in the capital stock per
worker) is the difference between gross investment per worker (sy) and the level of break-even
investment per worker (n+δ)k.
The intuition underlying this equation is not too difficult to follow:
pf3
pf4
pf5

Partial preview of the text

Download The Slow Diagrams - Intermediate Macroeconomics Analysis | ECON 202 and more Study notes Economics in PDF only on Docsity!

Fall Semester ’05-’ Akila Weerapana

Lecture 4: The Solow Diagram

I. OVERVIEW

  • In the last lecture, we discussed the importance of economic growth, and the importance of models. We then derived a model of economic growth: the Solow growth model, which basi- cally consisted of two equations: a production function and a capital accumulation equation.
  • In today’s lecture, we will first transform these equations into per-capita terms: in other words write the equations in terms of output and capital per-capita. This will make the model more tractable. We will then use these two equations to draw a diagram known as the Solow diagram.
  • We will then use this diagram to do various “comparative statics” exercises where we analyze the impact of changes in saving rates, population growth rates, the capital stock etc. on economic growth in the short run and in the long run.

II. THE PER-CAPITA VERSION OF THE SOLOW MODEL

  • In order to make working with the model a little easier, we transform the model into per- capita terms. Define the following per-capita variables y = YL (output per worker) and k = KL (capital per worker)
  • Note that every person is a worker in this model. I will use per-capita and per-worker interchangeably.)
  • The production function can be written in per-capita terms as YL = K αL 1 −α L ≡^

Kα Lα^ which means that y = kα

  • The capital accumulation equation can be written in per-capita terms as well.

k =

K

L

k˙ k

K

L

k^ ˙ k

(sY − δK) K − n ≡

(sY ) K − δ − n k^ ˙ k

(sY /L) K/L − (δ + n) ≡

(sy) k − (δ + n)

⇒ k˙ = sy − (δ + n)k

  • This equation states that net investment per worker (the change in the capital stock per worker) is the difference between gross investment per worker (sy) and the level of break-even investment per worker (n + δ)k.
  • The intuition underlying this equation is not too difficult to follow:
  1. Gross investment per worker is equal to savings per worker (From gross investment = savings).
  2. Some of this new capital per worker must be used to replenish depreciated capital per worker (δk). In addition for every worker, there are n new workers entering the economy, each of whom require k units of capital (nk) to keep capital per worker unchanged.
  3. The basic intuition is that unless you replace worn out capital and provide each new worker with the same amount of capital, then capital per worker in the economy will fall. So the level of break-even investment per worker (the amount of investment per worker necessary to leave capital per worker unchanged) is equal to (n + δ)k

III. THE SOLOW DIAGRAM

  • The two equations of the Solow Model can be written in per capita terms as

y = kα k^ ˙ = sy − (n + δ)k

  • We combine these 2 equations graphically into a diagram, known as a Solow diagram. The Solow diagram plots savings per worker and the break-even level of investment per worker as functions of the capital stock per worker (k).
  • Some features of the diagram:
    1. (n + δ)k is a straight line from the origin with slope = (n + δ).
    2. y = kα^ is a concave function. For those of you who are mathematically inclined: you can show that dydk = αkα−^1 > 0 is an increasing function of k and that the slope of y falls as k increases: d

(^2) y dk^2 =^ α(α^ −^ 1)k

α− (^2) < 0 because α < 1.

  1. sy is just a dampened version of the y curve because s is a constant fraction between 0 and 1.
  • The Solow diagram looks as follows.

6

Investment per worker

kt

sy ≡ skα

y ≡ kα

(n + δ)k

k∗

--- 

  • EXAMPLE 1: An increase in the savings rate. An increase in s will shift the savings line up. At the initial steady state, we will be investing more than we need to break even so the level of capital per worker will rise. This will continue until the new steady state at k 1 ∗ is reached. -

6

Investment per worker

kt

skα

s′kα

(n + δ)k

k∗ 0 k∗ 1

66 6


  • EXAMPLE 2: An increase in the growth rate of population. An increase in n will shift the break-even investment line up. At the initial steady state, we will be investing less than we need to break even so the level of capital per worker will fall. This will continue until the new steady state at k∗ 1 is reached. -

6

Investment per worker

kt

skα

(n′^ + δ)k (n + δ)k

k∗ 1 k∗ 0

6

6

6



  • EXAMPLE 3: A sudden increase in the capital stock. If K rises suddenly then k will rise as well, say to k 1 on the Solow diagram. At k 1 , we will be investing less than we need to break even so the level of capital per worker will fall. This will continue until the economy returns to the old steady state. -

6

Savings,Investment per worker

kt

skα

(n + δ)k

k∗ 0 k 1