Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Revenue and Duration of Oral Auction - Education and Computer | 300 350, Papers of History of Education

Material Type: Paper; Class: 300 - EDUCATION & COMPUTER; Subject: EDUCATION; University: Rutgers University; Term: Unknown 1990;

Typology: Papers

Pre 2010

Uploaded on 09/17/2009

koofers-user-u7i
koofers-user-u7i 🇺🇸

1

(1)

10 documents

1 / 16

Toggle sidebar

This page cannot be seen from the preview

Don't miss anything!

bg1
Revenue and Duration of Oral Auction
Junmin Shi
Department of Supply Chain Management & Marketing Sciences
Rutgers University, Business School-Newark and New Brunswick
Abstract
This paper investigates the revenue and duration of a hybrid oral auction (English auction and
Dutch auction) that is extensively adopted in practice, for instance the Christie’s. Unlike sealed
bid auction, oral auction is featured by its complexity of dynamic process. The bidding price
varies as a stochastic time series. Thereby, the duration of oral auction performs randomly as
well as its revenue. From the seller perspective, both the revenue and the duration are important
in designing the auction, especially how to choose the starting bid. In this paper, the bidding
process is decomposed into two phases: English auction (descending-bid) and the Dutch
auction (ascending-bid). For each phase, by the Markov tool, we derive the expected revenue
and duration as a function of the starting bid. As an example, an auction with a large number of
bidders is studied.
1. Instruction
As a powerful and well-known tool in business markets, auction plays an important role in
selling objects especially for antiques and art. With a long history around the world auctions are
very common for the commodities such as tobacco, fish, cattle, racehorses, and anything that
has a market of multiple people interested in purchasing. The main reason why auction is so
common is that a group of people are interested in buying the same object, and offering bids on
the object. As a tool, auction decides the winner (usually the highest bidder).
Nowadays, the auction theory has been well studied. Generally, there are traditionally four
types of auction that are used for the allocation of a single item: The four standard single unit
auctions are the English auction, the Dutch auction, First-Price Sealed-Bid auction, and the
Second-Price Sealed-Bid auction (for more details please see C. W. Smith 1990).
Open Ascending-bid auctions (English auctions) is commonly referred to as oral outcry
auctions, in which the price is steadily raised by the auctioneer with bidders dropping out
once the price becomes too high. This continues until there remains only one bidder (the
highest bidder) who wins the auction at the current price.
pf3
pf4
pf5
pf8
pf9
pfa
pfd
pfe
pff

Partial preview of the text

Download Revenue and Duration of Oral Auction - Education and Computer | 300 350 and more Papers History of Education in PDF only on Docsity!

Revenue and Duration of Oral Auction

Junmin Shi Department of Supply Chain Management & Marketing Sciences Rutgers University, Business School-Newark and New Brunswick

Abstract

This paper investigates the revenue and duration of a hybrid oral auction (English auction and Dutch auction) that is extensively adopted in practice, for instance the Christie’s. Unlike sealed bid auction, oral auction is featured by its complexity of dynamic process. The bidding price varies as a stochastic time series. Thereby, the duration of oral auction performs randomly as well as its revenue. From the seller perspective, both the revenue and the duration are important in designing the auction, especially how to choose the starting bid. In this paper, the bidding process is decomposed into two phases: English auction (descending-bid) and the Dutch auction (ascending-bid). For each phase, by the Markov tool, we derive the expected revenue and duration as a function of the starting bid. As an example, an auction with a large number of bidders is studied.

1. Instruction

As a powerful and well-known tool in business markets, auction plays an important role in selling objects especially for antiques and art. With a long history around the world auctions are very common for the commodities such as tobacco, fish, cattle, racehorses, and anything that has a market of multiple people interested in purchasing. The main reason why auction is so common is that a group of people are interested in buying the same object, and offering bids on the object. As a tool, auction decides the winner (usually the highest bidder).

Nowadays, the auction theory has been well studied. Generally, there are traditionally four types of auction that are used for the allocation of a single item: The four standard single unit auctions are the English auction, the Dutch auction, First-Price Sealed-Bid auction, and the Second-Price Sealed-Bid auction (for more details please see C. W. Smith 1990).

  • Open Ascending-bid auctions (English auctions) is commonly referred to as oral outcry auctions, in which the price is steadily raised by the auctioneer with bidders dropping out once the price becomes too high. This continues until there remains only one bidder (the highest bidder) who wins the auction at the current price.
  • Open Descending-bid auctions (Dutch auctions) in which the price starts at a level sufficiently high to deter all bidders and is progressively lowered until a bidder indicates to buy at the current price. The bidder wins the auction and pays the price at which they bid.
  • First-price sealed-bid auctions in which bidders place their bid in a sealed envelope and simultaneously hand them to the auctioneer. The envelopes are opened and the bidder with the highest bid wins, paying a price equal to the exact amount that he or she bid.
  • Second-price sealed-bid auctions (Vickrey auctions) in which bidders place their bid in a sealed envelope and simultaneously hand them to the auctioneer. The envelopes are opened and the bidder with the highest bid wins, but paying at the second highest bid.

One of the most remarkable results in auction theory is the revenue equivalence theorem, which was first introduced by Vickrey (1961). Two auctions are said to be " revenue equivalent " if they produce the same expected sales price. This is an important issue to a seller who wants to hold an auction to sell the item for the highest possible price. If one type of auction is found to generate higher average sales revenue, then that type auction will obviously be preferred by the sellers. In other words, the revenue equivalence theorem states that, if all bidders are risk-neutral bidder and have independent private value for the auctioned items, then all four of the standard single unit auctions have the same expected sales price (or seller's revenue).

In the auction study, an increasing number of empirical auction studies use a structural econometric approach within the theoretical framework of the independent private values model and the common value model (Hendricks and Paarsch 1995 and Laffont 1997). In common value auctions, a bidder's value of an item depends entirely on other bidders' values of it. By contrast, in private value auctions, the value of the good depends only on the bidder's own preferences.

In auction design, efficiency and optimality are the two primary goals in any auction design: the former focuses on the social welfare of the whole seller-bidder system, whereas the latter emphasizes the revenue-maximizing from the seller’s perspective (Zhan and Shen 2007).

Unlike sealed bid auction, oral auction is featured by its dynamic process property. In practice, oral auction is widely preferred than sealed bid auction. For instance, Christie's has auctioned off artwork and personal possessions via oral auctions. Christie's was founded in London, England, on 5 December 1766 by James Christie. Christie's soon established a reputation as a leading auction house, and took advantage of London's new found status as the major centre of the international art trade after the French Revolution. Christie's has held the greater market share against its longtime rival, Sotheby's, for several years and is currently the world's largest auction house by revenues. In addition to Christie's, there are various world famous auction organizations in which oral auction is generally adopted.

To sell an object via oral auction, the auctioneer begins the auction with an announced starting bid. For the bid, the auctioneer will ask the bidders for their response by open cries. If nobody responses for the bid, then the auctioneer announce “Going once” for a short while. If there is no response from bidders, then “going twice” is announced for another short while. If no response again, then the auctioneer deduces the bid, and ask the response. The similar

(^00 5 10 )

20

40

60

80

100

120

Time

Bidding Price

Bidding Process

Starting Price

Ending Price

Fig. 1 An example of the bidding process.

From the auction process described above, we have some conclusions the as follows,

  1. All the items could be auctioned off since any bidder is willing to take the auction at a

low enough price, say P 1. Therefore, the final bid of the auction is above P 1.

  1. Within the bidding process, there are two bidding phase: descending and ascending. In the descending phase, bidding price decreases from start price to the lowest bid. While in the ascending phase, bidding price increases from the lowest bid to the final bid.

S B

B

F

  1. The value of for bid governs the bidding process. If , that is,

there is bidder who is willing to take the object with bid , then the auctioneer will

increase the bid to. Let

N (^) i ( T ) Pi Ni ( T )> 0

P i

Pi (^) + 1

Pr{ N (^) i ( T ) = 0 }= qi

i

. (2.1) Thereby, Pr{ N (^) i ( T ) > 0 }= 1 q. (2.2)

Generally speaking, there are three typical processes which are possibly incurred in practice.

Case 1. Descending-bid (Dutch auction) Phase

As shown in Fig. 2, the bidding is monotonously decreasing from starting price to final bidding.

S

F

(^00) 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5

5

10

15

20

25

30

Time

Bidding Price

Bidding Process Starting Price

Ending Price

Fig. 2, Descending-bid process.

Case 2. Ascending-bid (English auction) Phase.

As shown in Fig. 2, the bidding is monotonously increasing from starting price to final bidding.

S

F

(^200) 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

110

Time

Bidding Price

Bidding Process

Starting Price

Ending Price

Fig. 3, Ascending-bid process.

Case 3. Hybrid bidding

2 2 3 3 4 4 5

q q q q q q q

+

= ⎜⎜⎜^ ⎟⎟

⎜^ − ⎟⎟

M

= i

i

. (2.8)

The reason goes as the follows. For any i > 1 , ⎡⎢⎣ (^) M (^) +⎤⎥⎦ ( , ) (^) i i = Pr{ N (^) i ( T ) = 0 ] q, (2.9)

and

+ (^) ( , i i + 1 ) Pr{ N^^ i ( T^^ )^^0 }^1 q

⎣ M^ ⎦.^ (2.10)

Since any bidder would definitely take the auction at price P 1 , we have

+ ( , ) 11 Pr( N T^ 1 (^ )^^0 )

⎣ M^ ⎦ ,^ (2.11)

and

+ ( , ) 1 2 Pr( N^ 1 ( T^ )^^0 )

⎣ M^ ⎦ (2.12)

For any other element where j i or j i + 1 ,

⎡⎢⎣ (^) M + ⎤⎥⎦ ( , ) (^) i j = 0. (2.13)

3. Revenue of Oral Auction

Let the expected revenue of the auction starting at Pk be denoted by

R P ( (^) k )= E ⎡⎢⎣ F S^ = Pk ⎤⎥⎦ (3.1)

In the following, we consider the revenue in descending-bid, ascending-bid and hybrid auctions.

3.1. Descending-bid phase

During the descending-bid process with the starting bid , the probabilities for

, , , …, are listed as follows.

S = P k

F = P k Pk (^) 1 Pk (^) 2 Pl

Final bidding price F (^) P F S ( = Pk )

P k ( 1 qk ) qk (^) + 1

Pk (^) 1 qk ( 1 qk (^) 1 ) qk

Pl (^) + 1 q qk k (^) 1 q k (^) 2 " ql (^) + 2 ( 1 ql (^) + 1 ) ql + 2

P l q qk k (^) 1 "q (^) l (^) + 1 ( 1 ql ) ql + 1

Note that

⎡⎢⎣( M− ) k^ − l^ ⎤⎥⎦ ( , l k )= q qk k − 1 ... ql (3.2)

Therefore, in ascending-bid process

1 1 1 1 1 1

l k k k l l l l l k^ l l k

P F P S P q q q q q q q

**− + +

  • − − − +**

= − ⎡⎢^ ⎤⎥

⎣ M ⎦

Accordingly, the expected revenue for the ascending-bid auction with the starting bid

S = Pl is given by

1 1 1 1 (^^1 ,

k k k (^) k l l (^) l k l l^ l

R P F S P

P q q

− − − = + +

= ⎡⎢^ = ⎤⎥

= − ⎡⎢^ ⎤⎥

(^) ⎣ M ⎦

E

)

3.2. Ascending-bid phase

In the ascending process with the starting bid , the probabilities for

, ,…, are listed as follows.

S = P l

F = P l Pl (^) + 1 Pm

where l k and l m,

1 1 1 1

1 1 1 1

( , ) ( , )

Pr( , ) ... ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

l m k m k l m l l k l m

k k l l m m

B P F P S P q q q q q q − − −^ + + + − + q

− + + +

= ⎡⎢^ ⎤⎥^ ⎡⎢^ ⎤⎥

⎣ M^ ⎦ ⎣ M ⎦

(3.8)

With starting price S = Pk, the expected revenue is given by

1

1

1

1

1 1 1 1

( , ) ( , )

( , ) ( , )

l k l m l k l m l

m

m

k

k l (^) m m l l k l m k l m l m (^) l k l m

R P F S Pk F S Pk B P

P q

P q

∞ − + = = ∞ − + = =

+

+

**− +

− + − +**

= ⎡^ = ⎤^ = ⎡^ ⎡^ = = ⎤⎤

⎢⎣ ⎥⎦ ⎢⎣^ ⎢⎣ ⎥⎦⎥⎦

= ⎡⎢^ ⎤⎥^ ⎡⎢^ ⎤⎥

= ⎡⎢^ ⎤⎥^ ⎡⎢^ ⎤⎥

M M

M M

E E E

(3.9)

3.4. An example of auction with a large number of bidders

In this subsection, we consider an oral auction where there are a large number potential

bidders and each of them responds to the auction announcement period at price with a

small probability , where and. To begin with, we give a limit

theory as follows.

n P i

p i pi ≥ 0 ∑ i = 0 1 2 , , ... pi = 1

Lemma 1 : Let be a binomial random variable with parameters , then

approached to Poisson random variable with parameter as n gets large

and gets small.

X ( n p , ) X

λ = np

p

Proof: since X is binomial, we have

1

(^1 1 )

(^1 1 1 )

Pr( )! ( ) ! ( )! ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ! ( ) ( ) (^) ( ) / ( !

i n i

i n i i (^) n i i

X i n p p i n i n n n i i n n n n n i n i n

= −^ −^ + −

= −^ −^ + −

λ λ

λ λ λ (^) ) n

Then, for n large enough and p small enough, we have the following limits,

lim (^^1 )^^ (^^1 )^1 n i

n n n i →∞ n

" − + (^) = , lim ( 1 ) n n (^) n e

− →∞ −^ =^

λ (^) λ , lim ( 1 ) i 1 n →∞ −^ n =

λ (^).

Hence, Pr(^ )^ !

i X i e i

= = λ^^ λ. (Q.E.D)

Following Lemma 1, for a large and small , the amount of bidders responding

within unit time is Poisson random variable with parameter. It follows that

the number of responding bidders within the announcement period T , denoted by

follows a Poisson distribution , that is.

Let , then

n pi

λ i (^) = n pi

) n n p T

i

p

N (^) i ( T ) Poisson ( λ (^) i T Poisso ( (^) i ) α = nT

Ni ( T ) ∼ Poisson ( α p ). (3.10)

Accordingly,

qi = Pr( N T i ( ) = 0 ) = exp (− α i ). (3.11)

and Pr( N Ti ( ) > 0 ) = 1 exp (− α pi ).

Substituting Eq. (3.11) into Eq. (3.8), we have

exp 1 1 1

Pr( , ) ( ln( exp( )))

l m k k m m i l i (^) j l j

B P F P S P

p (^) + = + p =

= − α α (^) + (^) ∑ − − α p

j

Thereby,

1 1

( ) exp ( (^) 1 ln( 1 exp( )))

k m l m l

k m R Pk P pm (^) i l pi (^) j l p

∞ = = = +^ =

= (^) ∑ ∑ − α (^) + − α (^) + (^) ∑ − − α

(3.13)

Shown in Fig. 4 is the functional relationship between the expected revenue and the starting bid. Graphically, the peak point in the curve represents the optimal starting bid which maximizes the expected revenue.

(^20 5 10 15 20 25 30 )

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

Time

Bidding price

Time Series of Bidding

Starting

Ending

Fig. 5, Time evolution of a bidding process.

Let denote the time length for bid , where can take value of , ,

or. For any bid , let denote the probability of there is no

response during period

X i Pi Xi T 1 T 1 + T 2

T 1 + T 2 + T (^) 3 Pi qi j ,

T j , where j = 1 2 3 , , , that is

q (^) i j , = P( N (^) i ( T (^) 1 ) = 0 ). (4.1)

Lemma 2. For any bid Pi , the following holds

1 1 1 2 1 2 1 2

, , , , ,

[ | ( ) ]

( (^) i ) ( ) (^) i ( (^) i ) (^) i i ( i

Xi N (^) iT T q T T q q Tq q q q

E

(^1) i , 3 )

. (4.2)

Proof. The conditional probabilities are given as

1 1 1

P( | ( ) ) Pr(^ (^ )^ )^ , Pr( ( ) )

i i i i i i

N T q X T N T N T q

>^ −

,

1 2

1 2 1 2

, ,

Pr( ( ) )Pr( ( ) ) P( | ( ) ) Pr( ( ) ) i (^ i ) i

i i i i i

N T N T

X T T N T

N T

q q q

and

1 2 3

1 2 3 1 2 3

, , ,

P( | ( ) )

Pr( ( ) )Pr( ( ) )Pr( ( ) Pr( ( ) ) i i (^ i ) i

i i i i i i

X T T T N T

N T N T N T

N T

q q q q

X

X

.

Then, the proof is completed by the definition of conditional expectation. (Q.E.D)

Let denote the time length of the bidding process with the starting bid

, the lowest bid and the final bid. Thereby

T k (^) → → l m

S = P k B = Pl F = Pm

1 1

l m k l m i j m i k j l

T X X

− → → + = =

= (^) ∑ + (^) ∑ +. (4.3)

Note there is no response for any bid along the descending-bid process, and the final bid. Eq. (4.3) is roughly simplified as

m Tk (^) → → l m = k l + T + (^) j = l j. (4.4)

Therefore, the duration for the auction with starting bid Pk is,

Auctions , Canadian Journal of Economics, Canadian Economics Association, vol. 28(2), pages 403-26, May.

  1. J. Laffont (1997), Game theory and empirical economics: The case of auction data ,

European Economic Review.

  1. Zhan R. L., Shen Z. J., (2006), Optimality and Efficiency in Auctions Design: A Survey,

working paper.